The Kelly Criterion: Maximizing Growth with Optimal Bet Sizing

The Kelly Criterion: Maximizing Growth with Optimal Bet Sizing

The Kelly criterion is one of the most influential strategies in betting and investing for determining how much of your bankroll to wager when you believe you have an edge. In this post, we'll cover the traditional formula, derive it step by step, and introduce an alternative formulation that reframes the problem in a more intuitive way.


1. The Standard Kelly Criterion

The classical Kelly formula for a binary bet is expressed as:

$$f^* = \frac{p \cdot b - (1-p)}{b}$$

where:

  • \(p\) is your probability of winning.
  • \(1-p\) is your probability of losing.
  • \(b\) represents the net profit per unit wagered (i.e., if you bet $1 and win, you gain \(b\) in profit).

Understanding the Terms

  • Expected Net Winnings:
    When you wager $1, your expected net profit is:
    $$p \cdot b - (1-p)$$
    This figure represents your "edge"—how much advantage you have on each dollar bet.
  • Optimal Fraction:
    Dividing the edge by \(b\) (the net gain per dollar bet) gives you the optimal fraction of your bankroll to bet, ensuring you maximize the logarithmic growth of your wealth over the long run.

2. Derivation of the Kelly Criterion

Understanding where the Kelly formula comes from can help clarify its assumptions and limitations. Here's how we derive it from first principles.

Setting Up the Scenario

Assume you have a bankroll \(W\) and you bet a fraction \(f\) of it. There are two outcomes:

  • Win:
    Your wealth increases by the net profit on the wager. Your new wealth becomes:
    $$W_{\text{win}} = W \times (1 + f b)$$
  • Loss:
    You lose the fraction of your bankroll you bet, so your wealth decreases to:
    $$W_{\text{lose}} = W \times (1 - f)$$

Maximizing Logarithmic Growth

The Kelly criterion aims to maximize the expected logarithmic growth of your wealth, which is more appropriate over many repeated bets. The expected log growth \(g(f)\) is:

$$g(f) = p \ln(1+fb) + (1-p) \ln(1-f)$$

When you reinvest your gains, your wealth grows multiplicatively rather than additively. The logarithm turns multiplication into addition, making it much easier to calculate long-term growth. Maximizing the expected log wealth is equivalent to maximizing the geometric mean return.

Finding the Optimal Fraction \(f^*\)

To find the optimal \(f^*\), we differentiate \(g(f)\) with respect to \(f\) and set the derivative equal to zero.

Step 1. Differentiate \(g(f)\):

$$g'(f) = \frac{d}{df}\left[ p \ln(1+fb) + (1-p) \ln(1-f) \right]$$

Using the chain rule:

$$g'(f) = \frac{pb}{1+fb} - \frac{1-p}{1-f}$$

Step 2. Set the Derivative to Zero:

For maximum growth, set \(g'(f) = 0\):

$$\frac{pb}{1+fb} = \frac{1-p}{1-f}$$

Step 3. Solve for \(f\):

  1. Cross-multiply to eliminate fractions:
    $$pb(1-f) = (1-p)(1+fb)$$
  2. Expand both sides:
    $$pb - pbf = 1-p + (1-p)fb$$
  3. Collect like terms (group the terms with \(f\)):
    $$pb - (1-p) = fb(p + (1-p))$$
  4. Simplify since \(p + (1-p) = 1\):
    $$pb - (1-p) = fb$$
  5. Solve for \(f\):
    $$f = \frac{pb - (1-p)}{b}$$

This is the standard Kelly formula.


3. An Alternative Formulation

While the traditional form is mathematically robust, it can sometimes be mentally cumbersome. An alternative way to express the Kelly criterion is by using gross winnings instead of net winnings.

Switching to Gross Winnings

Define:

$$r = b + 1$$

Here, \(r\) represents the total payout multiplier on your wager. For example, if you win a double-or-nothing bet, then \(r = 2\).

The Break-even Point

In terms of \(r\), the break-even win probability is:

$$p = \frac{1}{r}$$

For instance, in a double-or-nothing scenario (\(r = 2\)), you must win at least 50% of the time to break even.

Reformulating the Kelly Fraction

Rewriting the standard formula using \(r\) (by substituting \(b = r-1\)) gives:

$$f^* = \frac{rp - 1}{r-1}$$

This can also be rearranged to:

$$f^* = \frac{p - \frac{1}{r}}{1 - \frac{1}{r}}$$

Intuitive Interpretation

Imagine a probability scale from 0 to 1:

  • The break-even point is at \(1/r\).
  • If your estimated probability \(p\) is just above \(1/r\), you have a small edge and should bet a small fraction of your bankroll.
  • As \(p\) approaches 1 (a sure win), the fraction you bet increases proportionally.

For example, consider a bet where:

  • \(r = 2\) (double-or-nothing, so the break-even probability is 0.50),
  • And your estimated \(p = 0.80\).

Then:

$$f^* = \frac{0.80 - 0.50}{1 - 0.50} = \frac{0.30}{0.50} = 0.60$$

meaning you should bet 60% of your bankroll.


Alternatives

Approach Key Characteristics Advantages Disadvantages Typical Applications
Kelly Criterion - Maximizes expected logarithmic wealth growth
- Derived from log utility assumptions
- Mathematically optimal for long-term growth
- Minimizes risk of ruin over many bets
- Highly sensitive to errors in probability/edge estimates
- Can be very aggressive with high short-term volatility
- Assumes an infinite time horizon and log utility
Gambling (e.g., blackjack, sports betting), repeated investment opportunities
Fractional Kelly - Uses a fixed fraction (e.g., 50% or 25%) of the full Kelly stake - Reduces volatility and drawdowns
- Provides a buffer against estimation errors
- Sacrifices some growth potential
- May be overly conservative if estimates are very accurate
Trading, gambling, personal investing where risk management is paramount
Fixed Fraction Betting - Bets a constant percentage of the bankroll regardless of perceived edge - Simple and easy to implement
- Robust when probability estimates are uncertain
- Not optimized for maximizing growth
- Doesn't adjust for varying edge or odds
Recreational gambling, beginners, and situations where edge is hard to quantify
Expected Utility Maximization (Alternative Utility Functions) - Maximizes expected utility using functions other than logarithmic (e.g., CRRA, CARA) - Tailors bet size to an individual's specific risk aversion
- May be more realistic for personal preferences
- Can be complex to compute
- Requires subjective utility function selection
- Often lacks closed-form solutions
Financial portfolio optimization, personal investment decisions
Modern Portfolio Theory (Mean-Variance Optimization) - Balances expected return against variance
- Focuses on diversification across multiple assets
- Widely used and well-understood
- Accounts for diversification and risk-return trade-offs
- Assumes normally distributed returns
- Sensitive to estimation errors in means and covariances
- May overlook tail risk
Institutional portfolio management, asset allocation
Risk Parity / Value-at-Risk (VaR) Approaches - Allocates capital so that each asset contributes equally to overall risk
- Emphasizes downside risk
- Strong focus on risk control and protection against extreme losses
- Promotes diversification
- Can be overly conservative
- Depends heavily on risk model accuracy
- May ignore growth opportunities
Institutional investors, asset allocation strategies
Optimal f Rule in Trading - Similar to Kelly but adjusted for real-world constraints (e.g., transaction costs, liquidity) - More realistic for active trading environments
- Accounts for market frictions and operational limitations
- Requires additional parameter calibration
- May change frequently with market conditions
- Less mathematically elegant
Active trading, markets with significant transaction costs or liquidity issues

Conclusion

The Kelly criterion is a powerful framework for determining bet size, maximizing long-term growth while protecting against ruin. We started with the standard form:

$$f^* = \frac{p \cdot b - (1-p)}{b}$$

and then derived it step by step by maximizing the expected logarithm of your wealth. Finally, we introduced an alternative formulation using gross winnings:

$$f^* = \frac{p - \frac{1}{r}}{1 - \frac{1}{r}}$$

which provides a more intuitive perspective by relating your estimated win probability \(p\) to the break-even point \(1/r\).

Whether you prefer the traditional form or the alternative approach, understanding the derivation and intuition behind the Kelly criterion can empower you to make smarter decisions in situations of uncertainty. Feel free to share your thoughts or ask questions—exploring different perspectives on risk and reward only makes us better decision-makers in the long run!